22 Investment Risk Management
r
People cannot predict probability or severity of events with consistency. In the financial
world, this leads to either bias of “things won’t be that bad”, or, the risk-averse “I fear
the $100 loss more than I want the $200 gain”. This is sometimes referred to as the “loss
aversion” principle.
r
The law of small numbers means that insignificant or unrepresentative samples of events
can lead to an imbalance in opinion. Advertising and media coverage can be partly held
responsible for an irrational tendency to purchase slim chances of getting rich. US, UK and
Spanish optimistic folk buy their national lottery tickets in the extreme hope of winning.
r
People are less accurate in their view of randomness, e.g. in gauging whether dice or cards are
biased. Mental accounting and character judgement are clouded by non-financial influences.
r
Assessment of real probability is hampered by emotion. Recollection of more emotive or
recent events blurs possible from probable. The mass-buying hysteria in the dot-com craze
and other investment bubbles is compatible with such experiences.
r
People cannot construct probability or preference models consistently because any complex
data collation exercise demands a more stringent methodology.
So, academic theories of estimated probabilities and expected utility and profit are of du-
bious worth because investors are both fallible and irrational.
2
The very tendencies of the
same professional folk who manage investments and design risk management systems may be
compromised by this same inherent bias.
Nevertheless, a lot of work has been done dealing with risk and return to move us away
from our incorrect probabilistic judgement in the inexact science of portfolio management.
PORTFOLIO MANAGEMENT
We are constantly looking for a better portfolio with an improved calculus of risk versus return.
It is often thought that we can build optimal portfolios with the data given.
Much of the bedrock was formed in the seminal work by Harry Markowitz in 1952.
3
We
first started by assuming that capital markets have full competition, and we have participation
of rational, well-informed investors. This market is known as “efficient”. All securities are
known and understood so that return increases with risk. Risk is measured in a manner based
upon market price sensitivity called beta (β).
This means that an asset’s beta is 1.00 when it fully reflects the movements of a benchmark,
i.e. they move in tandem. This gives us a picture of market risk, so that a beta significantly above
1.00 means that the asset amplifies the market’s movements. This volatility is traditionally
viewed as risky.
We can thus put in stocks or bonds with a negative covariance or beta of −1.00 to protect
the net value of the portfolio. This is the familiar technique of hedging to lock in your current
value of asset. You can amalgamate a set of financial instruments of defined betas to build
a desired portfolio. The investors can use their full knowledge in the transparent market to
construct “efficient” portfolios to maximise return for risk.
Thus, we can derive an optimal risk-return point for each investor. Establishing an optimum
risk-return point on the preference curve gives us the “best investment” for the market player.
This theory is known as the capital asset pricing model (CAPM), and it forms the bedrock of
much investment theory. It is used in many universities and financial institutions for creating
an “efficient portfolio”. See Figure 3.1.
2
For example refer to “Anomalies: risk aversion”, M. Rabin and R. Thaler, Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol.15, no.1, 2001.
3
“Portfolio selection”, H. Markowitz, Journal of Finance, March 1952.