Cambridge Histories Online © Cambridge University Press, 2008
P1: JMT
0521812909c01 CB929-Bulmer 052181290 9 October 6, 2005 13:30
Globalization in Latin America before 1940 37
backlash on the continent after the 1870s.
37
Yet this continental move to
protection is pretty minor compared with the rise in tariff rates over the
same period in Latin America, and this for a region that has been said to
have exploited the pre-1914 global boom so well.
The interwar surge to world protection is, of course, better known.
The first leap was in the 1920s, which might be interpreted as a policy
effort to return to the protection provided before the war. It might also
be attributable to postwar deflation. Inflations and deflations seem to have
influenced tariff rates in the 1910s, the 1920s, and some other times, a so-
called specific-duty effect to which we return later in this section. The sec-
ond interwar leap in tariff rates was, of course, in the 1930s, with aggressive
beggar-my-neighbor policies reinforced by the specific-duty effect. Except
for the two that had the highest prewar tariffs, Colombia and Uruguay,
tariffs rose everywhere in Latin America. Still, for most Latin American
countries, tariff rates rose to levels in the late 1930s that were no higher
than they were in the belle
´
epoque.
38
But note the really big fact in Figure 1.4.Weare taught that the Latin
American reluctance to go open in the late twentieth century was the
product of the Great Depression and the delinking import substitution
strategies that arose to deal with it.
39
Yet, by 1865, Latin America already
had by far the highest tariffs in the world, with the exception of the United
States. At the crescendo of the belle
´
epoque, Latin American tariffs were at
their peak, and still well above the rest of the world.
Apparently, the famous export-led growth spurt in Latin America was
consistent with enormous tariffs, even though the spurt might have been
even faster without them. Latin American tariffs were still the world’s high-
est in the 1920s, although the gap between Latin America and the rest had
shrunk considerably. Oddly enough, it was in the 1930s that the rest of the
world finally surpassed Latin America in securing the dubious distinction of
being the most protectionist. By the 1950s, and when import-substituting
37
Charles Kindleberger, “Group Behavior and International Trade,” Journal of Political Economy 59
(February 1951): 30–46;Paul Bairoch, “European Trade Policy, 1815–1914,” in Peter Mathias and
Sidney Pollard, eds., The Cambridge Economic History of Europe,vol. 3 (Cambridge, 1989).
38
Of course, quotas, exchange rate management, and other nontariff policy instruments served to
augment the protectionist impact of tariff barriers far more in the 1930s than in the belle
´
epoque,
when nontariff barriers were far less common.
39
Carlos D
´
ıaz-Alejandro, “Latin America in the 1930s,” in Rosemary Thorp, ed., Latin America in
the 1930s (New York, 1984); Alan Taylor, “On the Costs of Inward-Looking Development: Price
Distortions, Growth, and Divergence in Latin America,” Journal of Economic History 58 (March
1998): 1–28.