
Poor Relief
in
Industrial
Cities
263
unions' relief expenditures (Ashforth 1985: 78-9, 81). For the five years
ended Lady Day 1861, irremovable paupers accounted for 62.2% of
relief expenditures in Bradford, 60.8% of expenditures in Manchester,
and 39.6% of expenditures in Sheffield (Ashforth 1985: 81).
The Settlement Law and the power of removal saved urban industrial
unions in Lancashire, Cheshire, and the West Riding perhaps £50,000 to
£80,000 per year. If manufacturers paid 35% of the poor rate, as was
assumed above, then the Settlement Law saved them £17,500 to £28,000
per year. The total income transfer from rural taxpayers, non-labor-
hiring urban taxpayers, and nonsettled urban workers to manufacturers
therefore was on the order of £67,500 to £88,000 per year.
34
Given that
savings rates varied across income classes, the income transfer caused
capital accumulation to increase by perhaps £15,000 to £20,000 per
year.
35
However, the Settlement Law also might have had a negative effect
on industrialization. If migration from the agricultural south to the north-
west was slowed by rural workers' fear of removal, then the Settlement
Law fostered a misallocation of labor and slowed the rate of economic
growth. It was determined in Section 2, however, that the selective use
of the power of removal by textile manufacturing cities should not have
deterred able-bodied young adults from migrating to urban areas. More-
over, urban Poor Law unions often granted relief to temporarily unem-
ployed nonsettled workers, which reduced the risk associated with migra-
tion and therefore should have increased the number of migrants. In
sum, urban poor relief had a positive (but small) impact on the English
economy during the first half of the nineteenth century.
34
This estimate was obtained by adding the estimated annual transfer from non-labor-
hiring urban taxpayers to manufacturers resulting from the use of the Poor Law as an
unemployment insurance system (£50,000-£60,000) and the estimated annual transfer
from rural taxpayers and nonsettled urban workers to manufacturers resulting from the
Settlement Law (£17,500-£28,000).
35
1 assume that the savings rate of manufacturers, farmers, and landlords was 30%, that
the savings rate of non-labor-hiring taxpayers was 5-10%, and that workers did not
save.
Crafts (1985: 124-5) estimated that the savings rate of farmers and landlords was
30%
and that the savings rate out of nonagricultural nonlabor income was "not . . . less
than 23 per cent." I assume that textile manufacturers' savings rate was the same as that
of farmers and landlords. Von Tunzelmann (1985: 215) and Crafts (1985: 124) conclude
that "saving out of
wages
was zero." See also Fishlow
(1961:
36). Feinstein
(1978:
76, 93)
estimated that fixed capital formation averaged £50.5 million per annum in the 1840s,
and that
25%
of total investment (£12.6 million) was devoted to industrial buildings and
machinery. If one-third of industrial investment took place in Lancashire, Cheshire, and
the West Riding, then the Poor Law caused capital formation in manufacturing to
increase by 0.4-0.5%.