authoritarian regimes displaying strong patrimonial features.
2
The Nazarbaev
regime can be described as a neo-patrimonial type, which combines personal or
patrimonial use of authority to procure loyalty and compliance with emphasis on
an efficient, Western-style system of administration. The constitution and subse-
quent decrees, amendments and legislation have placed unlimited political and
constitutional powers in the office of the President, who exerts legal and personal
influence over major organs of the government. Presidential patronage has
conferred considerable economic power and political influence upon the various
kin, clients and loyal supporters of the President.
3
In all Soviet successor states, state-sponsored transition to a market and
‘nomenklatura’ privatization have enhanced the incumbent elite’s capacity to
procure a loyal clientele by mobilizing ethnic, clan, regional and other personal
connections. It is common knowledge that all key sectors of the government (national
security, taxation, media) and the economy (oil and gas, metallurgy, telecommu-
nications, banking) in Kazakhstan are under the personal control of Nazarbaev
and his ‘extended family’ (bol’shaia sem’ia) of family, friends and clients.
4
Kazakhstan has attempted to establish legal-rational authority, a professional civil
service, the rule of law, a multiparty system, and promoted ‘democratization’
within the framework of a strong patrimonial presidency. Nazarbaev spelled out
his plans for reforms and the democratization of Kazakhstani society in the
well-known strategy Kazakhstan 2030, which was inaugurated in October 1997
and spelled out a plan for ‘prosperity, security and improvement of the welfare of
the citizens of Kazakhstan’.
5
The capture of key institutions and resources by the Soviet-era republican
national elites, who have retained their positions in the new post-Soviet states, has
many parallels with the new states in postcolonial Africa. In both contexts, the
practical exigencies of nation- and state-building policies and the alien and often
artificial nature of the modern institutions introduced by the colonial
state appeared to facilitate the rise of personalist or patrimonial rule, anchored in
the authority of one leader or ‘big man’.
6
However, the post-Soviet pattern of
nationalization, understood as a Kazakhization of the government and administrative
structure, has at least two distinctive elements that distinguish it from the pattern
of patrimonial rule in a number of postcolonial African states. The first is the
apparent ease with which the Soviet-installed national elites have succeeded in
accumulating power and resources through privatization, pushing out rival ethnic
contenders and, in particular, curtailing the political and economic influence of
Russians. Having inherited the state’s apparatus, means of exerting ideological
and social control and surveillance techniques, the communist-turned-nationalist
elite has bolstered both its formal and informal control over political, economic,
informational and ethno-cultural domains. Second, whereas the postcolonial state
in Africa has been seen as ‘weak’, the target of competing claims by rival ethnic,
clan, regional and other collective interests and numerous regional ‘strongmen’,
7
the post-Soviet state in Central Asia has inherited a strong coercive and
infrastructural capacity. The ‘weak state, strong society’ framework applied by
some scholars to understand several postcolonial Asian and African states does
not encapsulate the conditions prevalent in Central Asia where a Soviet-inherited
The nationalizing state: symbols and spoils 141