
//INTEGRAS/KCG/P AGIN ATION/ WILEY /WPS /FINALS_1 4-12- 04/0470855088_ 10_CHA09 .3D – 182 – [169–196/28]
20.12.2004 9:27PM
in order to avoid this cost. However, there are still problems related to the design of the
exchange and the required forecasts as discussed in Section 9.4.1.
9.4.3 The market control value of wind power
In Sweden, primary and secondary control are handled through the so-called balance
responsibility. The Electricity Act states that:
An electricity retailer may only deliver electricity at points of con nection where
somebody is economically responsible for ensuring that the same amount of
electricity that is taken out at the point of connection is supplied to the national
power system (balance responsibility).
This implies that someone has to take on the balance responsibility for each point with a
wind power plant – and the wind power owner has to pay for this. This means that
problems related to primary and secondary control are included in the market structure.
I am not aware of any detailed evaluation concerning whether these costs reflect the
‘true costs’ in the system. However, the TSO Svenska Kraftna
¨
t has to purchase any
additionally required dispatch from the market, which means that, at least, the suppliers
will be paid.
There may be problems regarding the competition in the so-called regulating market,
which corresponds to secondary control. A power system normally does not have so
much ‘extra’ reserve power, since the power system was dimensioned with ‘sufficient’
margins (i.e. very close to normal demand ). The owners of such regulating resources
tend to have little competition in cases when nearly all resources are needed. This means
that they can bid much higher than marginal cost, since the buyer of the reserves,
normally the TSO, has to buy, no matter what the price is. In a power system with
larger amounts of wind power, the requirement and use of reserve power will increase.
This means that, in a deregulated framework, there is a risk that profit maximisation in
companies with a significant share of available regulating power can drive up the price
for the regulation. This means that the price for regulating power that is needed to
balance wind power can increase, which means that the ‘integration cost’ of wind power
seems to be higher than the actual physical integration cost.
However, if competition is working, the daily control value wi ll be included in the
market, as the secondary control is used to handle the uncertainties. Again, the time
frame required by the bidding process is a problem (see Section 9.4.1).
The season al control value is included in the market since the prices change over the
year, corresponding mainly to a changed the hydro power situation.
9.4.3.1 Market multiyear control value
In this section, the impact of multiyear control on the value of wind power will be
illustrated with use of the example of the Nordic market, with its significant amount of
wind power. The prices in a hydro-dominated system will here be analysed in an
approximate way. The aim is to estimate an economic value of the yearly energy
production including the variations between different years.
182 The Value of Wind Power