Cambridge Histories Online © Cambridge University Press, 2008
lewis h. siegelbaum
the army, schools and other institutions.
38
However, the technocratic impli-
cations of NOT were not lost on the party, and most of the institutes and
laboratories promoting it did not survive the 1930s.
For workers there were more immediate concerns such as unemployment
which, despite the recovery of industry, grew throughout the 1920s. This was
due to a number of factors: the demobilisation of the army which threw sev-
eral million men onto the labour market, rural to urban migration, protective
legislation covering the conditions of employment for women and juveniles
and the cost-accounting basis (khozraschet) on which industry was compelled
to operate.
39
Between 1925 and 1928, the Commissariat of Labour recorded an
increase from approximately one million to 1.5 million unemployed, figures
that almost certainly understated the actual numbers. White-collar workers
comprised about one-third of the total, and women and youth were dispropor-
tionately represented.
40
The scourge of unemployment was mitigated for at
least some workers by a rudimentary system of unemployment insurance and
the maintenance of ties to the land, but many resorted to selling home brew
(samogon), and engaging in prostitution and thievery, petty and otherwise.
41
Workers with jobs in industry experienced a steady increase in their wages,
at least until 1927. Wage levels, based on collective agreements co-signed by
respective trade unions, were considerably higher in heavy industry where
the workforce was predominantly male than in textiles and other female-
dominated industries. Theyalso were some 80 per cent higher for technical and
office personnel than for blue-collar workers. Overall, wage increases outpaced
productivity gains, notwithstanding campaigns to reduce expenditures and
rationalise production processes.
42
These campaigns and other measures to
raise productivity did bring output levels within striking distance of pre-war
indices. Intensified after the introduction of the seven-hour work-day in early
38 Richard Stites, Revolutionary Dreams: Utopian Vision and Experimental Life in the Russian
Revolution (New York: Oxford University Press, 1989), pp. 145–59.
39 Lewis H. Siegelbaum, Soviet State and Society between Revolutions, 1918–1929 (Cambridge:
Cambridge University Press, 1992), pp. 100–7.
40 L. S. Rogachevskaia, Likvidatsiia bezrabotitsy v SSSR, 1917–1930gg. (Moscow: Nauka, 1973),
pp. 92, 147; E. H. Carr and R. W. Davies, Foundations of a Planned Economy, 1926–1929,
2 vols. (Harmondsworth: Penguin, 1971–4), vol. i,pp.486–90, 502–4.
41 Carr and Davies, Foundations, vol. i,pp.643–4; Chris Ward, Russia’s Cotton Workers and the
New Economic Policy: Shop-floor Cultureand State Policy, 1921–1929(Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, 1990), pp. 35–50; Jean-Paul Depretto, Les Ouvriers en U.R.S.S., 1928–
1941 (Paris: Publications de la Sorbonne, 1997), pp. 59–67; Nataliia Lebina, Povsednevnaia
zhizn’ sovetskogo goroda: normy i anomalii, 1920/1930gody (St Petersburg: Letnii sad, 1999),
pp. 51–67, 86–94.
42 Carr and Davies, Foundations, vol. i,pp.516–36, 1013–14; William J. Chase, Workers, Society,
and the Soviet State: Labor and Life in Moscow, 1918–1929 (Urbana and Chicago: University
of Illinois Press, 1987), pp. 217–43.
450