cessful transformation has been made possible by the government’s use of the
appropriate policy framework and industries’ active engagement. The government
set development goals that clearly indicate where the country should move for-
ward. Those goals and major policy directions have changed according to the stage
of development and in response to changes in domestic and international economic
conditions.
The government’s approaches have been practical throughout the years, and its
intervention has been pervasive, as manifested in economic planning. Also, there
have been several instances of trial and error, among them, the HCI plan, which
caused serious distortions in resource allocation and overinvestment. The Korean
government responded to the mistake through rationalization policies that aimed
to restore the market mechanism. In this regard, the role of the Korean government
is not a substitute for the market; rather, it has been successful because it has com-
plemented the functioning of the market, particularly in the earlier years when the
markets and institutions were still at an inceptive stage (Aoki, Kim, and Okuno-
Fujiwara 1997).
The government’s intervention into the market has not been uniform over the
years, as shown by the changes in the macroeconomic policy framework, which has
moved from direct intervention in the early years to liberalization and autonomy
more recently. Managing the economy to support industrialization has brought
tremendous benefits but also costs. Without the government’s intervention to mobi-
lize the limited resources toward a few targeted industries—under which a small
number of large firms enjoyed favorable conditions that fostered rapid growth—
Korea might not have built such modernized industries as steel, automobiles, and
shipbuilding. However, the cost of these industrial policies was not negligible.
Among other effects, the underdevelopment of the financial sector, which had
been subjected to the industrialization goals, not only caused losses in the financial
sector itself, it also had economy-wide impacts. The direct cost of the financial
repression in the early 1970s turned out to have negatively affected output growth
during the period, and its overall effects on the economy were significantly nega-
tive (Park, Song, and Wang 2004). In addition, the mismatch between the financial
system and the economic system as a whole has made the Korean economy vul-
nerable to outside financial shocks. Therefore, the Korean government’s efforts to
refurbish the economic system, including the financial sector in the early 1990s, did
not produce satisfactory outcomes as expected.
The government’s intervention in general brought about positive effects in two
areas: human resource development and S&T. Investment in public goods such as
education and innovation has always been advocated as one of the priority areas of
the Korean government, and the Korean case shows that practical and stepwise
approaches can be performed effectively in line with the overall stages of economic
development. A stepwise approach was used in both S&T and human resource
development in Korea. The primary policy goal in the earlier years was expanding
Overview of Korea’s Development Process until 1997 45
The role of the government in the Korean economy is not to substitute for, but to com-
plement, the functioning of the market.