506 Part Four • Microeconomics of Government and Public Policy
proposal goes through, but he or
she will appreciate the sacrifice.)
As an income group, those
under $30,000 will see 34 per-
cent of the proposed tax reduc-
tion. Those earning over $100,000
will get 29 percent of the cut. The
middle-income crowd will gar-
ner 37 percent of the proposed
tax relief. (Note to critics: that’s
the largest share.) One can jiggle
those figures around to argue
that some middle-income group
will see less of the cut than some
high-income group, but so
what? Regardless, the proposals
will shrink the individual bill for
just about everyone.
This is a problem?
Can Alberta Treasury afford
the $500 million tax cut? Yes.
And they owe it to us. This year,
the province will collect $4.2 bil-
lion in personal income tax in
1998–99. That’s $1 billion more
than three years ago. This year’s
total personal tax take also in-
cludes $350 million from the
high-income surtax and flat tax
imposed in the 1980s to fight a
deficit that disappeared five
years ago. Keep in mind that
part of the boom in personal in-
come tax revenues results from
bracket creep taxation. And need
we address the Canada Pension
Plan increases, which Alberta
agreed to and will take $320 mil-
lion more out of Albertan’s pock-
ets in 1999 than in 1998? On a
personal level, the CPP hikes will
cost a $35,800 salary an extra
$700 a year by 2003 when com-
pared with 1996. Both levels of
government should compensate
Canadians for that tax hike.
Despite this year’s small
provincial tax reduction, taxes
are still historically high in Al-
berta. Fifteen years ago, the
provincial income tax rate was
38.5 percent with no surtaxes on
top. Are critics of tax relief say-
ing Alberta cannot live with tax
rates closer to where they were
during the Lougheed era?
Of course, the province could
cut taxes without changing how
we calculate them. But de-link-
ing provincial taxes from Ottawa
means provincial taxes would no
longer be automatically raised
by federal bracket creep. And a
single rate would preserve pro-
gressivity in the tax system, but
without destroying the incen-
tives to work, save and invest, as
is currently the case under the
steeply progressive and punitive
Ottawa-linked rates.
There is nothing radical about
a single rate of taxation. Five
American states have a single
rate. Another nine have no state
income tax whatsoever. As for
the “flat” tax idea—it does exist
in Hong Kong, where the effec-
tive tax rate is 15 percent and
includes a generous basic per-
sonal exemption and charitable
deductions, which of course,
means it is still progressive.
Most important of all, if Alberta
implements a single rate and
combines it with overall lower
taxes, it will pressure the other
provinces and Ottawa to get
their high tax rates down. That
will promote saving, spending
and investing, which will in turn
have a positive effect upon job
creation.
Source: Calgary Herald Editorials,
November 4, 1998. Reproduced with
the permission of Mark Milke,
Alberta Director for the Canadian
Taxpayers Federation.
chapter summary
1. Majority voting creates a possibility of (a)
an underallocation or an overallocation of
resources to a particular public good and
(b) inconsistent voting outcomes. The median-
voter model predicts that, under majority
rule, the person holding the middle position
on an issue will determine the outcome of an
election involving that issue.
2. Public choice theorists cite reasons why gov-
ernment might be inefficient in providing
public goods and services: (a) There are
strong reasons for politicians to support spe-
cial-interest legislation; (b) Politicians may
be biased in favour of programs with imme-
diate and clear-cut benefits and difficult-to-
identify costs and against programs with