
2. We place the foreign sector—the “Rest of the World”—so that it interacts
with Canadian Product Markets. This sector designates all foreign nations
that we deal with and the individuals, businesses, and governments that make
them up.
Flow (13) in Figure 5-3 shows that people, businesses, and governments abroad buy
Canadian products—our exports—from our product market. This goods and services
flow of Canadian exports to foreign nations is accompanied by an opposite mone-
tary revenue flow (14) from the rest of the world to us. In response to these revenues
from abroad, Canadian businesses demand more domestic resources (flow 2) to pro-
duce the goods for export; they pay for these resources with revenues from abroad.
Thus, the domestic flow (1) of money income (rents, wages, interest, and profits) to
Canadian households rises.
But our exports are only half the picture. Flow (15) shows that Canadian
households, businesses, and government spend some of their income on for-
eign products. These products, of course, are our imports (flow 16). Purchases of
imports, say, autos and electronic equipment, contribute to foreign output and
income, which in turn provides the means for foreign households to buy Canadian
exports.
Our circular flow model is a simplification that emphasizes product market
effects, but a few other Canada–Rest of the World relationships also require com-
ment. Specifically, there are linkages between the Canadian resource markets and
the rest of the world.
Canada imports and exports not only products, but also resources. For example,
we import some crude oil and export raw logs. Moreover, some Canadian firms
choose to engage in production abroad, which diverts spending on capital from our
domestic resource market to resource markets in other nations. For instance, Nortel
has an assembly plant in Switzerland. Or flowing the other direction, Sony might
construct a plant for manufacturing CD players in Canada.
There are also international flows of labour. About 200,000 immigrants enter
Canada each year. These immigrants expand the availability of labour resources in
Canada, raising our total output and income. On the other hand, immigration tends
to increase the labour supply in certain Canadian labour markets, reducing wage
rates for some types of Canadian labour.
The expanded circular flow model also demonstrates that a nation engaged in
world trade faces potential sources of instability that would not affect a “closed”
nation. Recessions and inflation can be highly contagious among nations. Suppose
the United States experienced a severe recession. As its income declines, its pur-
chases of Canadian exports fall. As a result, flows (13) and (14) in Figure 5-3 decline
and inventories of unsold Canadian goods rise. Canadian firms would respond by
limiting their production and employment, reducing the flow of money income to
Canadian households (flow 1). Recession in the United States in this case con-
tributed to a recession in Canada.
Figure 5-3 also helps us to see that the foreign sector alters resource allocation and
incomes in the Canadian economy. With a foreign sector, we produce more of some
goods (our exports) and fewer of others (our imports) than we would otherwise.
Thus, Canadian labour and other resources are shifted towards export industries
and away from import industries. We use more of our resources to manufacture
autos and telecommunication equipment. So we ask: “Do these shifts of resources
make economic sense? Do they enhance our total output and thus our standard of
living?” We look at some answers next. (Key Question 4)
chapter five • canada in the global economy 107