8 Cultural patterning in Islamdom and the Occident 147
conclusion could eventually be drawn that the state had its own norms
not subject to the ethical considerations applying to private actions. The
Muslim principle, in contrast, denied any special status to public acts at
all,
stressing egalitarian and moralistic considerations to the point where
it ruled out all corporate status and reduced all acts to the acts of person-
ally responsible individuals.
It is incorrect, in this perspective, to refer to these as "private acts,"
since the antithesis public-private in social activity is precisely what the
Muslims denied while the Occidentals carried it to an extreme. Of
course, what I am speaking of here is a highly schematic perspective, of
limited reach. On neither side was the contrast carried out fully in the
Earlier Middle Period. Moreover, in some perspectives the difference
between Occident and Islamdom dwindles to the accidental.
In both cases, one can describe what happened, when the bureau-
cratic absolutism disappeared, as private possession of public office.
Among the Muslims, some sense of a public realm with its own norms
did not disappear. For instance, the position of the caliph, as certifying
agent legitimizing other rulers, retained an echo of that sense of a bu-
reaucratic public order which had been maintained in High Caliphal
times;
from this centralizing perspective, the rights of an amir and of an
iqta holder were public rights in private hands. In any case, it was
always realistically recognized that a king, at least, must act for his own
safety - for public reasons - in ways repugnant to proper ethics. Yet
both iqta holder and amir were thought of as individual men in direct
relations with other men - and this fact affected the manner in which
they could raise revenue, their relations to other officeholders, and even
the succession to their office.
Among the Occidentals, the devolution of authority to a multiplicity
of autonomous offices had threatened to wipe out that very distinction
between private and public which had been inherited from earlier times,
and to which the eager lawyers were trying to give such a broad effect in
the new setting. For a time, feudal relationships, for instance, could
have been interpreted in a highly contractualistic sense. But the most
characteristic drive was to reinterpret the devolution of offices and the
whole feudal system in a corporative sense, in which it was the office,
not the man, that was autonomous. Thus, on principles utterly alien to
Islamdom, even rights to the kingship of Jerusalem could be bought and
sold. However unrealistic in some ways, then, the two principles we
have contrasted make explicit certain attitudes that were singularly for-
mative in the two societies in the period.
These personal responsibilities of office in Islamdom were conceived